Feeds:
Posts
Comments

Archive for March, 2011

David French reflects on Reynolds’ Law (which I have discussed, and which Glenn Reynolds discussed on Tuesday) and its application to higher education:

When you believe, simplistically, that college somehow equals success, then vacuuming more people into college just makes sense. Yet you’re vacuuming in real people, not stimulus-response lab rats. And many of these real people are quite unprepared for traditional workloads, unused to academic discipline, and — worst of all — almost completely uninterested in the pursuit of knowledge. So you dumb down standards to keep them in, ramp up their free time, and voila, you end up with testimonials like a parent told me about her child in a freshman dorm at a certain unnamed SEC school (hint: Roll Tide!): “She sometimes dodges puddles of vomit on her way to the bathroom and about half the nights can’t even stay in her own room because her roommate is entertaining any one of her various hook-ups.”

My own daughters have not experienced this at their universities. But they attend (or attended—one just graduated in December!) relatively elite universities, and major(ed) in demanding subjects. Students in computer engineering, mathematics, and music are generally serious about what they’re doing. In schools a little lower on the food chain, however, and in less demanding subjects, things are different. I wrote in a comment to my earlier post:

The sad truth is that it’s possible to get a BA or BS without ever reading a book. Professors realize that students can’t or won’t do the reading, so we teach what we want the students to know and then test them only on what’s taken place in class. If I write an exam question that requires them to have done the reading by including something not covered in class, almost no one gets it right, and, worse, the few correct answers are randomly distributed, meaning even the students who got it right were guessing.

Many of the students we turn out are excellent. But many know very little. It’s not just the people in the liberal arts, either. Science, math, and engineering courses are geared to identifying the geniuses. If you’re not one, your success, or lack thereof, is fairly random. So, a lot of talented sub-geniuses drop out of those majors and a lot of semi-competent people get through.

The upshot is that degrees and even GPAs mean less and less, and an ability to discern real talent is worth more and more.

My only caveat is that “an ability to discern real talent” gets rewarded only to the extent that superiors have an ability to discern an ability to discern real talent. In fields where there are few objective measures, that’s too often lacking.

The applicability of Reynolds’ Law is, however, much broader than education. Bart Hall comments on French’s post:

I farm for a living — as in I have no off-farm job, and I refuse crop subsidies — and I can attest that the same phenomenon prevails in the agricultural world.

There are several states in which USDA subsidies constitute more than 100% of net farm income, which is to say that the average farm in those states is in a loss situation without the subsidies. The classic creativity and adaptability of independent farmers has been greatly undermined by subsidies, to the extent that many farmers are little more than welfare dependents.

There are plenty of additional examples, but the above ought to illustrate my point reasonably well.

I say, end all subsidies to everyone. Corporations, farms, NGO grants, the arts, sports, and all the like. The USDA spends $203,000 every year subsidising the Alabama Peanut Queen Festival. Why?

It’s a great point. Reynolds’ Law applies to almost everything that government subsidizes. I say almost everything, because subsidies are sometimes just graft. (The Alabama Peanut Queen Festival?) Let’s think through some of the applications of the general point that subsidizing markers undermines the traits that underlie them:

  1. Education. I’ve already talked about this, but it’s worth noting that subsidizing education doesn’t just undermine traits among students; it undermines the people (the faculty) and the institutions that depend on those traits and seek to instill and develop them. It changes the nature of schools, colleges, and universities, for it redirects their attention from students to satisfying government regulators and obtaining government support. It also undermines the value of the marker, the college degree, making the traits harder to recognize and reward.
  2. Housing. Subsidizing home ownership undermines saving, delaying gratification, investing in the future, and other traits associated with long-term achievement. It also undermines the institutions that depend on them and seek to instill and develop them. The same is true of rent subsidies and other housing and community development programs.
  3. Jobs Programs. Successful people tend to have good jobs. So, why not give people jobs to make them successful? Once again, that doesn’t develop the traits needed to keep a job and succeed at it; it undermines them. Many jobs programs actually have negative consequences, making it harder for people who have gone through them to hold a job subsequently. Why? In the program, there are limited consequences to bad behavior. A similar point, but with many more qualifications, might be made about affirmative action programs.
  4. Agriculture. Successful farms make money. So, let’s give farmers money. Then they’ll be successful, right? Well, no; their talents will be redirected away from farming toward obtaining subsidies.
  5. Welfare. Successful people have incomes. Why not give people incomes? That doesn’t make them successful; in fact it undermines incentives they would have to delay gratification, develop skills, hold a dull job for the sake of future advancement, etc. Subsidizing a lack of productivity, as a variety of thinkers have pointed out, discourages productivity.
  6. Social Security. Giving people subsidized retirement income doesn’t promote behaviors such as saving, investing, thrift, and self-restraint that in fact promote a comfortable retirement; it undermines them. It’s no surprise that the percentage of retirement income people draw from Social Security has been rising, while savings rates have been plummeting.
  7. Corporate Subsidies. Successful firms make money; why not subsidize small companies to help them become successful? In fact, why restrict this to small companies? Why not “make investments” to help corporations succeed, create jobs, and develop new technology? Doing that doesn’t encourage the traits that make companies successful; it undermines them by redirecting efforts from business to politics and lessening the consequences of both good and bad business decisions.
  8. The Arts. Nancy Pelosi told San Francisco artists that she wanted to subsidize the arts so that artists wouldn’t have to have day jobs. That plainly undermines useful traits in several ways. From the point of view of the arts alone, it redirects artists’ attention from their potential audience to the government and the grant panels that consist of fellow artists. It’s no surprise that the result is to drive artists away from producing what non-artists would be able to understand and appreciate.
  9. Science. Sciences and universities have become increasingly dependent on government grants. That redirects scientists’ attention from science to grant-getting, which itself undermines the traits needed for purely scientific success. I received several grants from the NSF early in my career, but stopped pursuing them precisely because of the distortions it introduced into my research and pattern of work.
  10. Energy. Subsidizing various forms of energy over others, and subsidizing conservation, undermines the traits that make utilities and their customers successful. Utilities used to devote themselves to providing the most reliable service at the lowest cost. Now, they are rewarded for making the grid less reliable and less adaptable by using technologies that increase costs.
  11. Trade Barriers. Protection from competition, in any form, insulates businesses from the pressures that develop successful strategies for competition and thus undermines the traits needed for long-term success.
  12. Health Care. Middle-class people tend to have adequate health care. But subsidizing health care insulates them from the pressures that would encourage them to make sensible decisions about health—everything from developing healthy habits to providing for their own health care and insurance to seeing a doctor when and only when it’s likely to do some good. Subsidies within the health care field, moreover, redirect attention away from helping the most people most effectively toward other goals, undermining the traits we have associated with success in doctors, nurses, and other health care providers.
  13. Transportation. Subsidizing the markers of success at individual (Cash for Clunkers?), community (light rail?), and regional (high-speed rail?) levels is not only wasteful, but directs planners, engineers, and ultimately travelers to less effective ways of moving from one place to another. Traits of seeking to maximize efficiency, minimize travel times, maximize safety, and minimize costs are undermined while traits of seeking other social “goods” and seeking government grants are encouraged.
  14. Unions. The preferential treatment given to unions under the Wagner Act and subsequent legislation at city, state, and federal levels (e.g., Davis-Bacon, as well as laws authorizing public sector unions) amounts to a subsidy for unionized workers that undermines the traits that make people successful employees and make organizations employing them successful. See the steel industry, the automotive industry—oh yes, and Wisconsin.

I could go on. But the point, I hope, is clear. Reynolds’ Law provides the basis for an argument against a very wide range of subsidies.

As the Cato Institute demonstrates, much of the current federal budget consists in just the kinds of subsidies that, according to Reynolds’ Law, are counterproductive. Eliminating such subsidies, even leaving Social Security, Medicare, and Medicaid off the table, would go a long way toward eliminating the deficit. Look at their recommendations for cuts. In many departments, it’s 90-100% of the department’s budget.

PS. Here’s a slideshow on free enterprise that features Reynolds’ Law alongside Friedrich von Hayek, Charles Murray, Marvin Olasky, and Thomas Sowell. What really hits the students are the pairs of photographs near the end, which show the same spot in 1990, after years of socialism, and in 2010, after years of free enterprise.

Read Full Post »

our stock price would be plummeting. That’s the upshot of this report, which is worth studying. The beginning:

Our country is in deep financial trouble. Federal, state and local governments are deep in debt yet continue to spend beyond their means, seemingly unable to stop. Our current path is simply unsustainable.

That’s what the Tea Parties have been all about. And that’s what the Left and the mainstream media desperately want to deny.

The Left tries to portray the Obama administration as well within history’s boundaries on the size and scope of the federal government. If we ignore the spikes caused by World Wars, however, that’s just not true. There’s been a drastic increase in the role of the federal government in the past century, and also in the past two years:

FDR took the federal government from 3% of GDP to about 10% of GDP, a vast increase. Obama has taken it from 19% to 25%—not quite as drastic an increase, to be sure—but to a level previously seen only at the height of World War II.

There are many reasons for the financial troubles of the United States, of course, but the report’s analysis makes it clear that entitlements are the chief source of the trouble. The Great Society was barely noticeable on the chart above, but that’s because the costs of LBJ’s programs were not immediate, but set on a path of very rapid growth:

That can’t continue, and, as Glenn Reynolds like to remind us, what can’t continue, won’t. We don’t have much longer before entitlements and interest swallow the entire federal budget:

That’s only 14 years away. No wonder there’s a growing movement of labor-skeptic Democrats. Can we raise taxes to deal with the problem? Look again at the slope of that line. Moving to European levels of taxation by doubling the federal tax take would delay the date of swallowing only by about 25 years.

Medicare and Medicaid, even more than Social Security, are the monsters threatening to swallow the entire federal government. In that sense, critics are unfair when they say that Obama concentrated on health care when he should have been concentrating on federal finances. Health care is the most important driver of our long-term budget difficulties. The accurate criticism, I think, is that he addressed the central long-term problem and got it wrong, following the model of the Great Society programs that got us into this mess rather than making hard choices to rein in growth.

Read Full Post »

My church has been having an adult Sunday-school class on immigration. They’ve hosted a Democratic state representative, a professor from the local seminary, etc., all on one side of the question. I’ve been stunned that people who think that there’s a right to immigrate and a corresponding duty (at least for Christians) to promote open borders feel no compulsion to listen to the other side. In particular, ask any of the advocates leading the class how they respond to the arguments of Immanuel Kant or John Rawls, the two philosophers who have written much about immigration from the point of view of ethical and political theory, and you get a blank stare.

Start with the idea of a social contract—the idea that, as the Declaration of Independence puts it, “to secure these [unalienable] rights, Governments are instituted among Men, deriving their just powers from the consent of the governed”—and the problem with justifying a right to immigration is obvious. People band together to form a government to protect their rights. A right to immigrate cannot be a natural right, for it makes essential reference to political organization, and so makes no sense in its absence. But it cannot be a civil right either, for the prospective immigrant is not a member of the political organization against whom he or she wishes to exercise such as right.

Kant observes this, and says that our obligation toward people in other nations is hospitality. In contrast to many contemporary Christians, however, he spells out carefully what this means. Kant uses a domestic analogy. Suppose some people show up at your door. You are obliged to be hospitable. What does that mean? You must not be uncivil; you must not harm them. But you are under no obligation to invite them in. If you do, you again must not harm them. But you are under no obligation to permit them to stay any longer than you want them to stay.

Rawls outlines the law of peoples, one of which is a law of noninterference: peoples must not interfere in the internal affairs of other peoples. But it’s important to note what’s not there. Peoples do not have a right to immigrate into another people’s territory without their consent. Indeed, recognition of such a right would contradict the law of noninterference. Peoples may restrict immigration to protect their own cultures and governing principles.

Kant and Rawls argue that there is no right to immigrate. They do not argue that countries or peoples should not admit immigration; that is up to the host country, and there may be good reasons to allow and even encourage immigration. But a country that restricts immigration, or allows immigration only of certain kinds, or from certain areas, does not violate anyone’s rights.

Read Full Post »

Charlie Sheen Cartoons

These are awesome—check out all of them:

Read Full Post »

Art should challenge the status quo, the staid complacencies of the bourgeoisie; it should even shock. So goes a standard Leftist line. But when art actually DOES that, they do their best to suppress it. That helps to explain why the ideas of the avant garde have been the same for more than a century, and why, today, avant garde means defending the statist status quo.

James Panero and Roger Kimball show us what’s been banned at the Pratt Institute:

Read Full Post »

Follow

Get every new post delivered to your Inbox.

Join 54 other followers